SHIUR #3: SHVEH KESEF                by Rav Mosheh Lichtenstein

 The opening mishna in Kiddushin states that a man can  marry a woman by giving her money (kesef) or goods (shveh  kesef).  The first method, kiddushei kesef, is treated  extensively by the gemara (3b), but marriage by giving goods,  kiddushei shveh kesef, is not elaborated on in the same  fashion.  We would like, here, to examine the process of  kiddushin by shveh kesef, and, hopefully, we will thereby  reach a better understanding of the essence of kiddushin  itself.

The formula in the mishna states that a woman may be  married by giving her a coin worth a peruta, or goods of  equivalent value (bi-peruta u-beshaveh peruta).  We would like  to begin by inquiring as to the relationship between these two  methods.  Is there essentially one type of kiddushin that can  be achieved by either mechanism, or does the existence of two  methods perhaps indicate that there are also two different  concepts of marriage itself?  If there are two different types  of marriage corresponding to the two methods, kesef and shveh  kesef, what is their nature and how is each accomplished?

The question of the biblical source for this expansion of  kesef to include shveh kesef, shall serve as a point of  departure for our discussion.  The gemara (3b) deliberates at  length to locate a biblical foundation for the fact that  kiddushin is achieved by monetary means, concluding that there  are two possible sources.  However, the gemara does not  provide any specific reference supporting the use of objects  in lieu of their monetary value.  Tosafot (2a) point to other  areas where the halakha clearly requires the use of money yet  allows the substitution of goods of equivalent value.  When  dealing with eved Ivri (purchase of a Jewish manservant) and  pidyon ha-ben (redemption of the first born), the gemara feels  obligated to provide a source for this ruling.  The gemara  does not assume as self-evident that equally valuable  commodities can replace currency.  However, regarding  kiddushin no source is required, indicating that the extension  to monetary equivalents is trivial.  The obvious question,  which Tosafot indeed ask, is what is the difference between  these various halakhic areas?

To answer this query, two possible approaches may be  taken:  1.  Either the premise underlying the question can be  denied (in this case, by supplying a hitherto unknown source  for kiddushin by shveh kesef), or 2.  The facts of the case  can be accepted and an explanation provided for the  divergence.  The truth, of course, is that these two options  are represented in a machloket rishonim (a disagreement among  medieval commentators).  Tosafot chose the former option,  adducing a new source for kiddushin, while Ramban preferred  the latter.  Tosafot claim that the validity of using shveh  kesef for the purposes of effecting marriage is derived,  apparently by analogy, from eved Ivri (purchase of a Jewish  slave), even though  there is no mention in the gemara of such  a comparison.  Similarly, Tosafot find sources for other such  cases in which objects can be used instead of money.  They  thereby create a uniform group of halakhot, all of which  permit the use of goods to replace money, yet require the  authority of an explicit biblical reference to support this  ruling.  Ramban, however, disagrees with Tosafot, and claims  that in the case of kiddushin, no specific source is  necessary, since the possibility of using a substitute can be  logically deduced from kesef.

To summarize, we have seen that there is a controversy  between Tosafot and Ramban as to whether the validity of using  shveh kesef can be derived from a-priori logic or requires a  prooftext.  Perhaps this controversy can shed light on our  original question - is shveh kesef an independent type of  kiddushin, or is it just a secondary branch of kiddushei  kesef.  Before proceeding, however, we must first understand  the underlying issues which are at the root of Ramban and  Tosafot's disagreement, and then return to see how this bears  on our question.

The word kesef (money), around whose meaning our entire  discussion revolves, can denote one of two things.  Either it  can signify a physical object, i.e. a coin, or it can refer to  an abstract value which is measured in monetary units.  Both  coin and value are represented by this term.  Therefore, when  dealing with a halakhic case involving currency, we must  always ask ourselves whether it is the former or the latter  that we are dealing with, since the two meanings refer to  different halakhic categories, each with unique requirements.

When talking about whether kesef means a coin or a value,  a distinction has to be made between the use of money for  ceremonial or symbolic needs, on the one hand, and the use of  money as a means of measurement in an exchange, on the other  hand.  In some cases, money is not handed over in exchange for  corresponding value being received, but rather serves in a  ceremonial role. Thus, for example, in pidyon ha-ben  (redemption of the first born), the handing over of the five  shekalim to the kohen does not redeem the child because the  kohen has received the child's worth, but rather a ceremonial  act of redemption was performed through the medium of  shekalim.  In such a case, due to the fact that the act of  redemption is a religious, and not a commercial, act, it is  quite clear that the money is fulfilling a ceremonial function  as a coin, and not representing actual value.  However, the  same may also apply to certain cases whose basic nature  belongs to the world of trade and commerce.  If the Empire  State Building (or any other real estate transaction) can be  bought and sold by the handing over of a single peruta  (roughly equal in value to a cent or two), we are not using  money for its value, but rather as a symbol, even though the  symbolism is meant to reflect actual transactions involving  value exchanges.  Though this is not a ceremony involving a  coin in the sense that pidyon ha-ben is, nonetheless, it is a  symbolic act, and not necessarily a transfer of value.  In a  word, money can be employed in a ceremonial or symbolic  capacity for a variety of purposes.

On the other hand, there are also many instances in which  money is utilized to execute transactions whose essence is the  transfer of value from one party to the other.  Here, the  monetary element serves as a universal standard of value  evaluation, and the accompanying purchasing power inherent in  the currency as a guarantee of the fairness of the purported  deal.  The seller transfers to the buyer merchandise of a  certain value and receives in lieu of this the corresponding  value in money.  Two values, one realized in cash and the  other inherent in an object, have been exchanged; the entire  transaction transpires between two real values and has no  symbolic element in it at all.

Perhaps the validity of using shveh kesef in place of  currency, depends upon which aspect of kesef is being used  within a given halakha.  If the money is serving in a  ceremonial or symbolic capacity, it will not be able to be  replaced by a different object of the same worth, unless there  is an explicit guideline in the Torah to validate the  substitution.  For it is the coin as a ceremonial object which  interests us rather than its value.  (An object of equal value  may be acceptable for the purposes of barter; however, as  objects, they are totally different.)  A coin is a coin, and a  horse is a horse; each object is distinct.  However, if an  exchange of value is taking place, there is no difference  between using money or goods of equivalent value, between cash  or commodities, because their status is equal insofar as both  have a specific value.  Thus, there is no need for a special  source to legitimize the use of shveh kesef in such cases  since there is no reason to distinguish between it and kesef.   However, in the previous example, where the object is required  for the ceremony, there is a major difference between the two  categories of kesef and shveh kesef, and no expansion of kesef  can be done without an explicit source.

Based upon this analysis, the dispute between Ramban and  Tosafot depends upon their understanding of the role played by  money in the process of kiddushin.  For though it is clear  that the act of kiddushin is the handing over of money from  the man to the woman with her consent, the meaning of this  exchange is much more problematic.  How can the establishment  of a personal relationship be achieved by the transfer of  monetary value?  Can love or loyalty be bought?  Although it  is obvious that a relationship is not commercial in nature,  nevertheless, kiddushin does work by monetary means.   Therefore, one of two possible approaches must be postulated.

1. Kiddushin is not the establishment of an interpersonal  relationship but rather the creation of a legal bond of  ownership between the two parties.  Such is the simple reading  of the sources the gemara cites for kiddushei kesef - either  "ki yikach" (when a man takes a wife) which is compared to the  acquisition of a field, or the analogy to the freedom of a  maidservant (amma ha-Ivria).

2. The use of money is not intended as a form of payment, but  rather serves to concretize the establishment of the personal  relationship.

[Lack of space and other considerations prevent us from  elaborating upon these approaches here; suffice it to say that  both can be illustrated in the sources relating to kiddushin.   We shall, therefore, limit ourselves to applying it to our  topic of monetary equivalents.]

Hence, if the marital framework is established by means  of the husband acquiring his wife, then the money is being  used for the value it represents in this exchange.  Therefore,  it is self-evident that the use of any form of value, be it  cash or commodity, should equally be valid.  Presumably, this  is exactly what Ramban meant when he wrote that:  "...wherever  it says that money is required for a transaction (ne'emar  kesef be-kinyan), goods of equivalent value are included...  regarding a purchase ("miknah") [no source is needed] since  ("nicha lei") he is as appreciative of the object of  equivalent value as he is of the money itself since both are  of equal value to him."

If, however, kiddushin is not to be understood as a  standard acquisition, then clearly the money is being used in  a symbolic or ceremonial role, in order to establish this  unique relationship.  Unless we have a clear source to allow  the use of shveh kesef, we would assume that only a coin may  be used.  Perhaps this understanding stands behind Tosafot's  need to bring a prooftext to allow kiddushin by shveh kesef.

At this point, it seems worthwhile to make a brief  summary of what we have seen until now.

 1.  The word money can mean two different things - the actual  currency, or the value it represents.  2.  Kesef refers to the coin as an object when used for  ceremonial or symbolic acts, and to the value it represents  when used in commercial transactions.  3.  Substituting goods for money is reasonable in exchanges  based on the value of the items involved, but not in those  where the object itself is required for symbolic or ceremonial  purposes.  Hence, in the former, simple logic allows the use  of commodities in lieu of currency, whereas in the latter, an  explicit source is required.  4.  The meaning of kesef in the various areas of halakha must  be determined based upon an independent analysis of each  particular case.  5.  Kiddushin can be understood either as a transaction  establishing a formal legal status of spousal obligation, or  as a means of addressing the interpersonal element.   6.  Ramban seems to understand kiddushin as a monetary  acquisition, and so the kesef is required for the value it  represents.  Hence no source is necessary to allow the use of  shveh kesef in place of kesef.  7.  Tosafot seem to understand kiddushin as the establishment  of an interpersonal relationship, and so the kesef is required  as a symbol.  Hence a source must be found to allow shveh  kesef to act as this symbol.

However, our understanding of Ramban's position seems  unsatisfactory.  For even if kiddushin is a standard monetary  transaction, it can not be an exchange of values between two  parties as it is in a commercial setting.

Firstly, it seems eminently clear that a person does not  purchase a wife as he does a field, as Ramban himself pointed  out elsewhere (Gittin 9a).  Kinyan kiddushin, 'to purchase a  wife,' clearly relates to a special bond within the laws of  personal status and not to the common concept of commercial  acquisition.  To be sure, the concept of purchase unique to  marital status is by no means romantic.  The relationship is  subject-object and not I-Thou.  Nevertheless, kiddushin is not  a commercial act.  Therefore, payment is out of place.  Hence,  the money which creates this religio-legal status is not  merely an object of value.

Secondly, even if we were to claim (as Tosafot themselves  may have done in Ketubot 2b) that the relationship established  by the gemara between buying a wife and buying a field is more  than a mere analogy, it does not necessarily follow that the  guiding principle is value.  We saw above that some  transactions can be enacted by a symbolic payment, and do not  require true exchange value.

Regarding kesef kiddushin, there is absolutely no doubt  in any mind that the money used is of a symbolic nature.  A  peruta (or any other sum, for that matter) does not reflect  the value of the woman.  Instead, it is a minimal sum required  for the symbolic effect of purchase. [Actually, Avnei Milu'im  (29:2) does claim that the money handed over for kiddushin is  for real value, but such an idea is totally untenable and,  presumably/hopefully, he did not show this piece to his wife.  (The book itself was published posthumously.)]

To summarize, even if kiddushin is an act of purchase,  the money required is not for its real value, but rather for  its symbolic significance.  Therefore, it is far from self- evident that goods of equivalent value can be substituted for  money, since we are not interested in the value, but rather in  the physical object known as a coin.  Since the function of  the money is either symbolic or ceremonial, a source must be  provided which recognizes the legitimacy of using other  objects for kiddushin.  How can Ramban, then, say that no  source is needed to allow shveh kesef?

As quoted above, Ramban compares kiddushin to commercial  transactions and concludes that since both are essentially an  agreement between two contracting parties, neither requires an  explicit source to allow the use of shveh kesef.  This  reasoning, however, is also enigmatic.  If kiddushei kesef is  a symbolic act, the parties' agreement should be irrelevant.   Only an object that is suited for a symbolic role can serve in  such a capacity, even if those concerned agree to use a  different item.

One possible explanation is that Ramban thought that  since the object has a certain value, and we need a symbol to  effect an acquisition, other objects can fulfill the desired  symbolical role as well as money.  If so, the argument between  Ramban and Tosafot is whether only money can be used for  symbolic transactions, as Tosafot thought, or whether other  objects will also suffice, due to their implicit value.

Such an approach, though, is not without its problems.   Firstly, there is a basic qualitative difference between a  coin and any other object.  Though an object has a certain  value, it is essentially a functional object.  A coin's very  essence, however, relates to measurement of value and has no  meaning otherwise.  Therefore, any other object is unsuited  for the symbolic representation of value, even if it is  valuable, while the coin perfectly addresses the symbolic  element.  Moreover, the comparison by Ramban between a  commercial transaction, in which real assets are being  transferred, and kiddushin, in which personal status is dealt  with, is also extremely problematic.  And finally, if this is  the explanation, the element of agreement is relatively  unimportant, while Ramban clearly emphasizes it.

Therefore, it seems preferable to offer a different  interpretation of Ramban's opinion which emphasizes the  element of consent.  Up to now, we have assumed that the basic  component of the act of kiddushin, in cases of kiddushei  kesef, is the transfer or handing over of the money from the  man to the woman.  [Although we mentioned wholly divergent  understandings of this event, the common denominator to them  all was this basic assumption.]  The rationale for this is  also quite clear; since the relevant references in the Torah  relate to the monetary element and Chazal refer to it as  monetary kiddushin (kiddushei kesef), presumably, this is what  it is.

However, a different approach is possible.  The gemara in  the beginning of the masekhet contrasts between the term used  by the Torah - kicha (purchase) - and that employed by Chazal  - kiddushin.  The meaning of the word kiddushin, as Tosafot  point out (2b), is designation.  This word was chosen because  by the act of kiddushin a relationship is established between  the husband and wife who designate each other as their spouse.   They thereby create the marital status and its accompanying  exclusivity and loyalty.  Thus, the concept of kiddushin  stands in contrast to that of kicha.  The latter emphasizes  the acquisitive nature of the marital process, and, therefore,  also displays a disparity between the two parties who are in  unequal positions in such a transaction.  'Kiddushin,'  however, is essentially an interpersonal relationship between  two people who share an equal status in the relationship.   Both of these approaches to marriage are expressed throughout  the masekhet.  (These approaches can also be readily  demonstrated from the Yerushalmi in the beginning of the  fourteenth chapter of Yevamot).  The clearest example of the  difference between the two types of marriage is the  distinction between kiddushin by money (kidushei kesef) and  kiddushin by intercourse (kiddushei bi'ah).  Clearly sexual  relations signify the interpersonal relationship, while giving  money effects an acquisition.  However, kiddushei kesef  themselves can be understood as having such a double track  (cf. Tosafot Kiddushin 7a s.v. Ve-nifshetu that expounds a  somewhat different duality within monetary kiddushin).  The  money can serve as the vehicle of acquisition by which the  husband claims his wife, yet it can also be utilized as the  expression by which a relationship is established.  It can be  not only a form of payment, but also a token of alliance and  association.  The husband's willingness to give, and the  wife's agreement to receive are indicative of the relationship  which they are forging together.  In a word, the essence of  the act of kiddushin is not the monetary transfer, but rather  the meeting of two minds and hearts as expressed through a  monetary agent.

This understanding of kiddushin enables us to understand  Ramban's opinion regarding shveh kesef.  If kiddushin is  established by means of a ceremonial use of money (in a manner  not dissimilar to pidyon ha-ben) or if it is a symbolic act of  acquisition, then certainly the Tosafot are more convincing.   Ramban, however, is relying upon the alternate form of  kiddushin in which the personal relationship is paramount, and  for whose purposes the interpersonal agreement is at the focus  of the procedure.  The transfer of money is merely an  expression of their agreement, and therefore, Ramban  emphasizes the element of agreement.  (This is similar to some  understandings of da'at in kinyan, the intentions of the  parties involved in monetary transactions.  Some Rishonim  understand that the transaction is effected by their  intentions, and not by the action involved.  Here we are using  that same principle, not to explain commercial transactions,  but to understand kiddushin.)  This being the case, if both  parties agree to use another object instead of money, there is  no reason to not to allow shveh kesef.

In conclusion, let us now return to the question which we  posed at the opening.  Does shveh kesef represent an alternate  form of kiddushin or a secondary route subordinate to the  basic case of kiddushin with actual money?  This is the issue  in dispute between Ramban and Tosafot.  According to Tosafot,  a special source is required to allow the use of objects in  place of money.  Since the role of money in the kiddushin  procedure is either ceremonial or symbolic, objects other than  money are indeed second-rate and remain so even after they are  included by virtue of a midrashic expansion.  However,  according to Ramban, two separate concepts of kiddushin may be  postulated; the first one, acquisitive kiddushin, is achieved  by use of symbolic money, and if a monetary equivalent is  valid in such cases, it must be based upon the authority of an  explicit source, as Tosafot claimed.  The other concept is  that of inter-personal kiddushin.  In this case, shveh kesef  indeed works, not as a secondary form of cash, but rather as  an equal means of generating agreement and expressing affinity  between the couple.

Be that as it may, the sources point to no qualitative  difference between the two options; each is equally valid to  achieve the desired kiddushin and to bring about "ahava ve- achva ve-shalom ve-re'ut" - love and kinship, peace and  friendship.

 Next Week's Shiur: ------------------

Next week, the shiur will discuss chalipin (barter)- the sugya  at the bottom of 3a, which concludes on the second line of 3b.   The shiur will refer to the Tosafot, the Ramban, and the  Rashba to that passage.

Guiding questions: 1.  Try to understand the basic difference between the reason  of the Gemara, as understood by Rashi, for the rejection of  chalipin, and the reason as understood by Tosafot. What, for  instance, would be a nafka mina (different ramification) of  the two explanations? 2.  Tosafot claims that the gemara is deliberating whether  chalipin is a kind of kesef or not.  Define the similarity and  the difference between the two. 3.  "Kicha kicha m'sdei Efron" - what exactly is derived?